Science & Technology Development Journal: Economics- Law & Management

An official journal of University of Economics and Law, Viet Nam National University Ho Chi Minh City, Viet Nam

Skip to main content Skip to main navigation menu Skip to site footer

 Review

HTML

98577

Total

980

Share

Mainstream theories of corporate governance and the corporate governance – firm performance relationship






 Open Access

Downloads

Download data is not yet available.

Abstract

This paper reviews the mainstream theories of corporate governance and the relationship between corporate governance structures and firm financial performance. We show that the four predominant theories often employed to study the corporate governance – firm performance relationship are agency theory, stewardship theory, resource dependence theory, and institutional theory. In spite of being an overwhelmingly predominant theoretical approach in corporate governance studies, agency theory has recently been criticized for not fully reflect corporate governance practices in various institutional contexts. It is, therefore, necessary to re-examine the traditional agency framework to understand the corporate governance – firm performance relationship in various institutional environments. There are also calls for the application of a multi-theoretical approach to capture the complex nature of the corporate governance – firm performance relationship. It is also clear from our review that the effect of corporate governance on firm performance is inconclusive as empirical findings concerning this relationship are mixed in different analysis contexts. It is argued that such inconclusive findings of the corporate governance – firm performance relationship may be caused by the national institution differences and the imperfection of estimation techniques. Several recent studies in corporate governance support the view that the implementation of corporate governance mechanisms in a country is influenced by its institutional environment. For this reason, the effectiveness of corporate governance mechanisms also varies from country to country, or in other words, it is country-specific. This suggests that future research focusing on cross-national comparative contexts may provide more insight or in-depth information on the corporate governance – firm performance relationship. We also suggest that the potential mediating impacts of institutional characteristics on the corporate governance – firm performance relationship should be taken into consideration when conducting cross-country comparative corporate governance studies.

INTRODUCTION

It is indicated that there are three primary sources of inspiration for most of the empirical studies in the field of corporate governance, including agency theory, stewardship theory, and resource dependence theory 1 . Among them, the agency theory is regarded as the overwhelmingly predominant theoretical approach in corporate governance studies 2 , 3 , 4 , 5 . However, scholars increasingly realize that the agency theory depicts only a part of the complicated picture of an organization 6 , and insufficiently presents corporate governance practices in all analysis contexts due to cross-national differences of the institution 7 . This leads to the need for the application of institutional theory to conduct cross-national comparative analyses of corporate governance

Consequently, there are recent calls for the application of a multi-theoretical approach to capture the complex nature of the corporate governance – firm performance (CGFP) relationship 2 , 4 , 7 , 8 , 9 , 10 , 11 , 12 . It is suggested that the agency theory should be complemented by stewardship theory 10 , by resource dependence theory 9 , 10 . It is also suggested that the choice of what theory to lay the foundation of the debate about corporate governance depends on our various study aspects, which can be generalized to four major groups, including (i) Economics and management; (ii) Culture and sociology; (iii) Law; and (iv) Politics 8 .

From the point of view of economics and management, in which corporate finance is one of the vital components, a large number of prior studies adopted agency theory as the major theoretic framework to investigate the CGFP relationship in diverse contexts of analysis 13 . More specifically, Letza, Sun, and Kirkbride 3 conclude that the finance view and agency theory are employed as the predominant approach of studies on corporate governance in the past decades.

This paper aims to review the mainstream theories of corporate governance and the relationship between corporate governance structures and firm financial performance. The paper proceeds with an overview of agency theory, stewardship theory, resource dependence theory, and institutional theory. The theoretical frameworks and typically empirical findings of the CGFP relationship will then be reviewed in the second subsection.

FOUR PREDOMINANT THEORIES IN CORPORATE GOVERNANCE RESEARCH

Agency theory

An agency relationship is defined as “a contract under which one or more persons (the principal(s)) engage another person (the agent) to perform some service on their behalf which involves delegating some decision-making authority to the agent” 14 . This implies that the separation between control functions (of agents) and ownership (of principals) in contemporary public corporations is a potential source of interest conflict between agents and principals, called the principal–agent problem. According to Eisenhardt 6 , the principal-agent relationship arises from three primary assumptions about people (both the owners and the managers are opportunistic, rational, and risk-antipathetic individuals), organizations (aim distinction among members and information asymmetry between the owners and the managers), and information (information is regarded as a purchasable commodity). Correspondingly, it is assumed that (i) both owners and managers are opportunistic, rational, and risk-antipathetic individuals; (ii) the goals of members in an organization are dissimilar and information asymmetry exists between owners and managers; and (iii) information is regarded as a purchasable commodity.

Agency theory, therefore, is generally concerned with aligning the interest conflictions between principals and agents. Jensen and Meckling 14 and Shleifer and Vishny 5 among others argue that inherently opportunistic managers tend to abuse a firm's resources to pursue their own egocentric benefits rather than those of the owners. Agency theory suggests that firms should establish appropriate governance structures to monitor the behaviors of managers and prevent owners from such abuses, i.e. mitigate the principal-agent problem 14 . Jensen and Meckling 14 also suggest that establishing these governance structures generates three different types of cost which shareholders have to bear: (i) Monitoring costs (expenditures by the principal to control the agent’s actions); (ii) Bonding costs (expenditures by the agent to make up to the principal for the agent’s harmful activities); and (iii) Residual loss (the decrease in the principal’s welfare caused by the separation between the agent’s decisions) 14 . However, the impacts of those costs can be minimized and firm financial performance may be enhanced provided that firms can establish effective governance mechanisms 5 . It is also necessary to distinguish between the terms of ‘system’ and ‘mechanism’ in the corporate governance literature. While the corporate governance system focuses on corporate governance at the country level, the term of corporate governance mechanisms refers to corporate governance at the firm level. More specifically, a corporate governance system deals with the legal framework, institutional and cultural factors of a country " shaping the patterns of influence that stakeholders exert on managerial decision-making" 15 . Whereas, the term of corporate governance mechanisms may be understood as the ways used to solve corporate governance problems at the firm level 16 . However, it should be noted that the term ‘system’ is sometimes used with the same meaning as ‘mechanisms’ 17 or ‘structures’ 7 . Many prior studies interchangeably use the term 'mechanisms' and/or 'structures' to deals with corporate governance at the level of firm.

The extant corporate governance literature 16 , 18 , 19 , 20 , 21 , 22 suggests some such mechanisms to align the interest conflicts between the owners and the managers, including internal mechanisms (such as board size, board diversity, board committees, board independence, managerial ownership, and leverage, among others), and external mechanisms (such as block-holder ownership, institutional ownership, the market for corporate control and managerial control, and legal framework). Although the above-mentioned dual classification of corporate governance mechanisms is widely accepted, it should be noted that the denotation of each category is various between scholars 16 and, in fact, most researches primarily focus on the impact of each mechanism of corporate governance on financial performance 13 , 21 . For example, in many corporate governance studies, board size, board diversity, board committees, and board independence (including board composition and board leadership structure) are regarded as determinants of the board attributes. It should also be noticed that there is no consensus among researchers about the connotation of the terminology “board attributes”. For example, Zahra and Pearce 23 state that there are four board attributes including (i) Composition; (ii) Characteristics; (iii) Structure; and (iv) Process. They demonstrate that board composition refers to the size of board and the combination of various types of directors (such as executive or non-executive directors). Board characteristics mention the experience, independence, industry background of directors. Board structure refers to the organization and allocation of personnel to board committees. Board process mentions the decision-making associated with the board's activities and styles. In line with previous research 24 , 25 , 26 , many studies consistently use the terms of board attributes or board structure to refer to the combination of size, committees, diversity, meetings, independence, and leadership structure of the board. Meanwhile, managerial ownership and block-holder ownership are two major features of the ownership structure. The choice of mechanisms to study will be based on the availability of data in each country under the current research.

Resource dependence theory

Resource dependence theorists take the view that a firm is an open social entity which is closely connected with the conditions of its environment, such as human resource, capital resource, and information 27 , 28 . In this regard, resource dependence theory suggests that the board of directors plays a crucial role in linking the firm and those social resources 27 , 28 . More specifically, the function of the board is to not only monitor managerial behaviors (as mentioned by agency theory) but also provide essential resources that are needed to enhance firm performance and/or ensure those resources via connections with the external environment 29 . Pfeffer and Salancik 27 assert that the board’s provision of essential resources includes: “(i) advice and counsel; (ii) legitimacy; (iii) channels for communicating information between external organizations and the firm; and (iv) preferential access to commitments or support from important elements outside the firm” 9 .

In other words, apart from the monitoring function, the board also serves as a resource provider. Hillman and Dalziel 9 refer to the ability of the board to bring essential resources to the firm as “board capital” including “human capital (experience, expertise, reputation) and relational capital (network of ties to other firms and external contingencies). They also state that the question examined by resource dependence theory is how such board capital can lead to a board’s provision of resources and subsequent firm performance. In summary, resource dependence theory offers two important implications regarding the board: (i) environmental pressures and demands may have impacts on board composition, and (ii) differences in board composition may result in various firm performance 28 .

For the region of East Asia, although there is preliminary evidence to state that resource dependence theory can better explain the board’s functions of East Asian companies than agency theory 30 , it is suggested that the combining of the two theoretical approaches will provide a sound grasp of the board’s functions 9 .

Institutional theory

Young, et al. 30 , based on studies of Orru, Biggart, and Hamilton (1997) and Peng (2000), state that the main reason for distinctions between board's functions of East Asian firms and those of Western firms is the differences of the institutional and regulatory environments between the two regions. This leads to the need for the application of institutional theory to conduct cross-national comparative analyses of corporate governance. Indeed, Aguilera and Jackson 8 strongly argue that “ comparative approaches to studying corporate governance must, by nature, deal with the diversity across countries and over time” (p. 491). So what is the role of institutional theory in comparative studies of corporate governance? and how can national institutions affect their corporate governance mechanisms?

The theory of institution is drawn from various domains of social science, such as economic, sociology, and political science 8 . From the perspective of economics and political science, ‘institution’ is defined as “ the humanly devised constraints that structure political, economic and social interaction. They consist of both informal constraints (sanctions, taboos, customs, traditions, and codes of conduct), and formal rules (constitutions, laws, property rights)31 . In short, institutions may be seen as rules and constraints designed to direct and justify the interactive behaviors of individuals and organizations.

Concerning the role of institutional theory in studying corporate governance, several recent studies 11 , 24 , 30 , 32 , 31 , 33 , 34 , 35 support the general view that the implementation of corporate governance mechanisms in a country is influenced by its institutional environment. For this reason, the effectiveness of corporate governance mechanisms also varies from country to country. It is suggested that the factors of the national institutional environment such as culture, financial system, corporate ownership patterns, legal tradition, and economic situation 36 , 37 are important determinants in analyzing different models of organization and their different levels of performance 38 , as well as in creating diverse national corporate governance practices 37 .

For instance, in terms of legal tradition, La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, Shleifer, and Vishny 39 , by investigating the nexus between legal tradition and corporate governance for a sample of 49 countries, show that the investor protection and the capital market development of civil law countries are weaker than those of common law countries, and as a result, the corporate governance codes of common law countries concentrate on protecting the shareholders’ rights. Similarly, Love 13 reviews previous research and realizes that whereas most extant studies are conducted on particular nations, some cross-national comparative analyses examine the CGFP relationship (firm-level) within the interaction with corporate governance system (country level). According to those several comparative studies, it is suggested that corporate governance at the firm level has more influence on firm valuation in countries with weaker legal protection 13 .

Moreover, in countries with incomplete legal systems and weak legal enforcement, corporate governance mechanisms may be adopted for legitimate targets rather than for firm performance 2 . Consequently, the nominal commitment of good corporate governance practice at the firm level is not necessarily to be the real implementation, and as such, cannot relate to firm performance. In that case, the corporate governance practice is a purely normal matter rather than fact 13 , 40 .

The above examples illustrate the impacts of the national institutional factors on corporate governance practices at the firm level as well as their importance to cross-country comparisons of corporate governance and firm performance. Based on a study of Aguilera and Jackson 34 , Ahrens, et al. 32 strongly argue that “ agency problems may vary across different national settings and implies that researchers should integrate the agency framework with institutional analysis to generate robust predictions. Future research should expand on this concept and seek to more explicitly examine the nature of agency conflicts and their implications in different institutional settings ” (p. 323). For this reason, cross-country comparisons of corporate governance and firm performance, despite at firm level or country level, must take into account the above-mentioned institutional factors. In general, although there is a growing consensus on the role of a national institution in corporate governance practices, cross-national comparative research on the CGFP relationship is still in the early stage of development 34 . Examining what institutional factors matter and how they affect corporate governance practices, therefore, is considered as the primary objective of comparative studies of corporate governance 12 , 32 , 34 , 41 , 42 .

Several recent studies have focused on the CGFP relationship in emerging markets, where legal environments, corporate governance systems, and institutional frameworks are considerably different from those of developed markets 22 , 43 , 44 , 45 , 46 , 47 . These studies indirectly show that empirical evidence obtained from various legal and institutional environments will not only significantly contribute to the extant literature of the CGFP relationship 48 , but also indicate that the unquestioning application of overseas corporate governance mechanisms but not take the distinctions of institution characteristics into consideration is not always the best choice 22 .

Stewardship theory

Whereas agency theorists view managers as opportunists, the proponents of the stewardship theory believe that they are naturally reliable individuals and tend to do good jobs to become good stewards of the company's resources, as well as to maximize the company's profit 49 . This means that, under stewardship theory, the managerial motivation is seeking to maximize the performance of an organization rather than pursuing individual self-interest as mentioned by agency theory. If that is the case, there is no reason to believe that the conflict of interest between the owners and the managers, as indicated by agency theory, is real.

As a result, stewardship theorists advise that managers should be fully empowered to effectively operate their organization by, for example, combining, rather than separating, the role of board chairman and chief executive officer (the CEO) in the sole position, known as the CEO duality 49 , 3 .

THE CORPORATE GOVERNANCE–FIRM PERFORMANCE RELATIONSHIP

The significantly positive relationship between corporate governance mechanisms and financial performance in large economies, especially in the US and the UK, is supported by most extant studies 21 . It is also argued that this relationship is stronger with market-based measures of performance and weaker with accounting-based measures 13 . However, the empirical findings concerning this link are mixed and inconclusive in different analysis contexts 22 . In a noticeable work, Ahrens, et al. 32 emphasize that " despite enormous volume of research, we still know very little about corporate governance. We cannot say, for example, that specific ownership or board structures lead to better economic performance" (p. 312). It is argued that such vague findings of the CGFP relationship may be caused by: (i) The institutional differences between countries 30 , 32 , 33 , 34 ; and (ii) The imperfection of measurement methods 13 , 19 , 32 .

The nexus between board attributes and financial performance

The board of directors is one of the vital determinants of the internal corporate governance mechanisms 50 and its relationship to financial performance has attracted many scholars for a long time 2 . Although such a relationship is explained and forecasted by several theories such as agency theory or resource dependence theory 9 , empirical findings of the influence of the board on firm performance are inconclusive 4 , 19 . The extant literature of corporate governance shows that the attributes of the board may include board size, board diversity, board committees, and board independence (including board composition and board leadership structure), among others. The next subsections will review the link between these board attributes with firm financial performance in the extant literature.

Board size and firm financial performance

Among various board characteristics, the size of the board of directors is believed to be one of the most essential characteristics 24 , 51 . Whereas the relationship between board size and firm performance is supported by agency, stewardship, and resource dependence theories, there is not a consensus among scholars about the direction of such a nexus in practice 51 .

Indeed, based on agency theory, M. Jensen 52 argues that firm performance will be able to be enhanced if the size of board is small and suggests that the optimal threshold of board size should not be over eight members. The perspective of keeping a small board size to function well is also achieved consensus by Lipton and Lorsch 53 ; Sonnenfeld 54 ; and Yermack 55 , among others. From the stewardship theory's perspective, Muth and Donaldson 26 provide a similar prediction that small boards positively impact firm performance. They argued that small boards react better to firm demands because they help directors to join in decision-making through effective interpersonal communication, as well as help in enhancing social cohesion. Based on resource dependence theory, Dalton, Daily, Johnson, and Ellstrand 51 recommend the opposite opinion that the larger size of board is, the better firm financial performance will be. Likewise, Firstenberg and Malkiel take the view that a small board of directors cannot offer a set of members with diverse managerial experience, gender, nationality, and as such, it may restrict its capabilities in terms of stimulating various perspectives.

Empirically, the link between board size and firm financial performance in the extant literature is inconclusive as well. Yermack 55 finds an inverse relationship between board size and market-based measurement of corporate governance (firm value) in a sample of 452 large United States industrial companies for the period of 1984-1991. His finding is consistent with the agency theory that small boards tend to perform more effectively than large ones. This view is supported by several recent studies of the CGFP relationship 56 , 57 . By contrast, Beiner, Drobetz, Schmid, and Zimmermann 58 use the data of firms quoted at the Swiss Exchange by the end of 2002 and develop a comprehensive system of seven simultaneous equations. Their study aims at examining the relationship between selected corporate governance mechanisms and firm valuation through applying the three-stage least squares method. Their research reveals that board size is positively related to firm value.

Besides, there is also empirical evidence that shows no statistically significant relationship between board size and financial performance. For example, Reddy, et al. 21 , using panel data for the NZX top 50 publicly-listed companies over the period 1999-2007 in New Zealand, discover that there is no statistical evidence to believe such a nexus is significant. Similarly, a study by Aljifri and Moustafa 16 , employing a sample of 51 firms listed in Dubai Financial Market and the Abu Dubai Securities Market, shows that board size has an insignificant impact on firm performance.

Meanwhile, another study by Mak and Kusnadi 57 , employing data from listed firms in Malaysia and Singapore, reveals that the relationships between board size and firm value (measured by Tobin’s Q) in both countries are inverse. It is to be regretted that the study of Mak and Kusnadi does purely use multi-national data to examine the role of board size to firm performance, but not use a comparative approach to clarify the nature of the board size-firm performance relationship in different national contexts.

Board committees and firm financial performance

Agency theory considers the monitoring of behaviors of managers (agents) to protect the interests of owners (principals) as the primary function of the board 6 , 14 . Thus, it is assumed that the more independent the board is from management, the better it will exercise its monitoring function. Seen from this point of view, Maassen 59 asserts that one of the strategies to mitigate the influence of management on board independence is the establishment of board committees and formal division of board roles in the organizational structure of the board. Independent boards, in turn, may have a positive impact on firm performance 26 .

Conversely, stewardship theory advocates that there is no conflict of interests between management, directors, and shareholders 49 , and therefore, the formation of board committees becomes unnecessary 59 . Instead, stewardship theory suggests that the board may become an important strategic means to maximize the benefits of shareholders once its power structure is united and is constituted by experienced members 3 , 49 , 59 . Seen from this point of view, it is argued that the separation of board authority structure may cause the trouble of information asymmetries and unnecessary bureaucratic structures that may hinder the strategic decision-making processes of firms (Maassen, 2002), and as a result, may have a negative impact on firm performance.

Board independence and firm financial performance

According to Muth and Donaldson 26 , the level of board independence is usually measured by two structural variables, including (i) Board composition and (ii) Board leadership structure. While board composition is often defined as the proportion of outside directors on the board, board leadership structure mentions whether a company has one position combining the duties of the CEO with those of the board chairman (known as the CEO duality or unitary leadership), or whether it allocates these positions to different members (known as the CEO non-duality or dual leadership) 10 , 20 , 25 , 26 , 41 , 60 , 61 . The direction of the influence of board independence on firm performance can be predicted by three predominant theories in corporate governance literature, including agency, stewardship, resource dependence, and institutional theories.

Agency theory suggests that the higher level of non-executive directors on the board is, the better the monitoring function of the board will be 10 , 14 , 50 . It is assumed that non-executive directors may exercise their monitoring function better than executive directors as they are less dependent on management and more interested in protecting their renown in the external labor market 50 . Nicholson and Kiel (2007) discuss that if the monitoring function of the board is implemented effectively thanks to board independence, the chance for managers to gain self-interest at the expense of shareholders will be minimized, and as a result, shareholders will obtain larger benefit.

Proponents of agency theory also argue that CEO duality hinders the board from implementing its monitoring function because when the CEO is also the board chairman, “ the impartiality of the board is compromised” 49 , and the power of monitoring can be abused for self-interests of the CEO. In other words, it is obvious that non-executive dominated board and CEO non-duality, seen from the agency theory’s perspective, are regarded as characteristics of an independent board which, in turn, result in better monitoring of self-interested behavior of managers 4 . It is reasonable to assume that both non-executive dominated board and CEO non-duality will lead to the diffusion and allocation of management decisions and monitoring decisions that help diminish agency problems 50 .

Conversely, stewardship theory suggests that executive directors can take advantage of information and knowledge about the corporation to make better decisions than those of non-executive directors 49 . More specifically, Muth and Donaldson 26 state that “ a majority of executive directors provides the depth of experience, technical expertise, and ease of communication needed for effective board functioning ” (p. 9). Being naturally trustworthy individuals and good stewards of the company's resources, executive directors tend to do good jobs, and as such, their decisions naturally aim at maximizing shareholders’ benefit 10 .

Hence, the stewardship theory forecasts that the higher proportion of executive directors will lead to high-quality decision-making and, as a result, have positive effects on firm performance 10 . tewardship theory also advises that managers should be fully empowered to effectively operate their organization by combining, rather than separating, the role of board chairman and the CEO 3 , 49 . CEO duality is assumed to offer a good grasp of the company’s operating environment 62 and a unification of direction and strong command and control 47 that will beneficially affect firm performance.

Resources dependence theorists are in favor of the stewardship theory's perspective on board composition. Daily, et al. 4 argue that non-executive directors provide an approach to vital resources of companies. To illustrate this point of view, they say that non-executive directors, “ who are also executives of financial institutions, may assist in securing favorable lines of credit ” (p.372); or non-executive directors, “who are partners in a law firm, provide legal advice, either in board meetings or in private communication with firm executives, that may otherwise be more costly for the firm to secure ” (p. 372). If that is the case, it is reasonable to infer that the higher presence of non-executive directors on the board will have a positive impact on firm performance.

The nexus between ownership structures and financial performance

Block-holder ownership and firm financial performance

From agency theory’s perspective, the concentration of ownership is considered as one of the important mechanisms to monitor managerial behaviors. The concentrated ownership by shareholders (such as institutional and individual investors, and block-holders) helps in reducing agency problems arising from the separation of ownership and control 5 . It is argued that the larger company stocks the block-holders own, the stronger power they will gain to make management serve their benefits 63 . Furthermore, holding a large proportion of company assets, institutional investors or block-holders have greater intensive to be involved in managerial behaviors to ensure that company's interests and their benefits are not expropriated, that, in turn, result in better firm financial performance 22 . However, while block-holder ownership is regarded as a mechanism to reduce the conflicts between shareholders and management, it may be a potential source of conflicts of interest between minority shareholders and majority ones 64 .

Managerial ownership and firm financial performance

Managerial ownership is usually defined as the stock ownership of a company inside managers (including executive directors, non-executive directors, and other senior managers). The relationship of managerial ownership and firm performance is predicted by two theoretical hypotheses in the current literature, consisting of the convergence-of-interests hypothesis and entrenchment hypothesis. The convergence-of-interests hypothesis, based on the agency theory’s perspective, suggests that increasing managerial ownership will result in diminishing the conflicts of interests between outside shareholders and inside managers 14 . The reason is when the managers owned a larger proportion of shares, their benefits will be more closely related to the other shareholders’ benefits. Therefore, maximizing the shareholders’ benefits, in this case, is synonymous with maximizing their wealth 25 . It is logical to infer that the harmonization of interests between inside managers and outside shareholders will be able to be achieved if the managers have further company stocks 48 . In other words, the larger the managerial ownership is, the more active the incentive for the managers to monitor their managerial behaviors will be that may mitigate agency costs and improve firm performance 21 , 65 .

In contrast, the entrenchment hypothesis proposes that when inside managers own a low level of company stocks, they, under the competitive pressures of market forces, may have a higher incentive to make suitable decisions for the benefits of the other outside shareholders 66 . However, it is also argued that when inside managers own a higher level of company stocks and have higher voting power to protect themselves from such pressures, they may pursue self-interests without effective monitoring 65 .

CONCLUSIONS

Based on the literature review, this paper summarizes four predominant theories often employed to study the CGFP relationship, namely agency theory, stewardship theory, resource dependence theory, and institutional theory. While most extant corporate governance studies base their arguments on the agency theory, scholars increasingly realize that the agency theory depicts only a part of the complicated nature of the CGFP relationship. Thus, there are recent calls for the application of a multi-theoretical approach to capture this complex nature. Second, although there is a growing consensus on the role of a national institution in corporate governance practices, cross-national comparative research on the CGFP relationship is still in the early stage of development. Third, empirical findings regarding the CGFP relationship are mixed and inconclusive. We conclude that most extant corporate governance studies focus on an individual country so they are unable to offer insights into the nature of the CGFP relationship in different analysis contexts.

LIST OF ABBREVIATIONS

CGFP relationship: The corporate governance-firm performance relationship

CEO: Chief executive officer

US: The United States of America

UK: The United Kingdom

NZX: New Zealand's Exchange

COMPETING INTERESTS

The author declares that they have no conflicts of interest

AUTHOR CONTRIBUTION

The author confirms sole responsibility for the manuscript preparation

References

  1. CLSA. Corporate governance watch 2010. Gill A, Allen J, Powell S, editors. Hong Kong: Credit Lyonnais Securities Asia; 2010. . ;:. Google Scholar
  2. Lynall MD, Golden BR, Hillman AJ. Board composition from adolescence to maturity: A multitheoretic view. Academy of Management Review. 2003;28(3):416-31. . ;:. Google Scholar
  3. Letza S, Sun X, Kirkbride J. Shareholding versus stakeholding: A critical review of corporate governance. Corporate Governance: An International Review. 2004;12(3):242-62. . ;:. Google Scholar
  4. Daily CM, Dalton DR, Cannella AA. Corporate governance: Decades of dialogue and data. Academy of Management Review. 2003;28(3):371-82. . ;:. Google Scholar
  5. Shleifer A, Vishny RW. A survey of corporate governance. The Journal of Finance. 1997;52(2):737-83. . ;:. Google Scholar
  6. Eisenhardt KM. Agency theory: An assessment and review. Academy of Management Review. 1989;14(1):57-74. . ;:. Google Scholar
  7. Young MN, Peng MW, Ahlstrom D, Bruton GD, Jiang Y. Corporate governance in emerging economies: A review of the principal-principal perspective. Journal of Management Studies. 2008;45(1):196-220. . ;:. Google Scholar
  8. Aguilera RV, Jackson G. Comparative and international corporate governance. Academy of Management Annals. 2010;4(1):485-556. . ;:. Google Scholar
  9. Hillman AJ, Dalziel T. Boards of directors and firm performance: Integrating agency and resource dependence perspectives. Academy of Management Review. 2003;28(3):383-96. . ;:. Google Scholar
  10. Nicholson GJ, Kiel GC. Can directors impact performance? A case-based test of three theories of corporate governance. Corporate Governance: An International Review. 2007;15(4):585-608. . ;:. Google Scholar
  11. Peng MW. Outside directors and firm performance during institutional transitions. Strategic Management Journal. 2004;25(5):453-71. . ;:. Google Scholar
  12. Nguyen T, Nguyen A, Nguyen M, Truong T. Is national governance quality a key moderator of the boardroom gender diversity-firm performance relationship? International evidence from a multi-hierarchical analysis. International Review of Economics & Finance. 2021;73(C):370-90. . ;:. Google Scholar
  13. Love I. Corporate governance and performance around the world: What we know and what we don't. The World Bank Research Observer. 2011;26(1):42-70. . ;:. Google Scholar
  14. Jensen M, Meckling W. Theory of the firm: Managerial behaviour, agency cost, and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics. 1976;3(5):305-60. . ;:. Google Scholar
  15. Weimer J, Pape J. A taxonomy of systems of corporate governance. Corporate Governance: An International Review. 1999;7(2):152-66. . ;:. Google Scholar
  16. Aljifri K, Moustafa M. The impact of corporate governance mechanisms on the performance of UAE firms: An empirical analysis. Journal of Economic & Administrative Sciences. 2007;23(2):71-93. . ;:. Google Scholar
  17. Denis DK, McConnell JJ. International corporate governance. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis. 2003;38(1):1-36. . ;:. Google Scholar
  18. Ang JS, Ding DK. Government ownership and the performance of government-linked companies: The case of Singapore. Journal of Multinational Financial Management. 2006;16(1):64-88. . ;:. Google Scholar
  19. Bhagat S, Bolton B. Corporate governance and firm performance. Journal of Corporate Finance. 2008;14(3):257-73. . ;:. Google Scholar
  20. Elsayed K. Board size and corporate performance: The missing role of board leadership structure. Journal of Management and Governance. 2011;15(3):415-46. . ;:. Google Scholar
  21. Reddy K, Locke S, Scrimgeour F. The efficacy of principle-based corporate governance practices and firm financial performance: An empirical investigation. International Journal of Managerial Finance. 2010;6(3):190-219. . ;:. Google Scholar
  22. Haniffa R, Hudaib M. Corporate governance structure and performance of Malaysian listed companies. Journal of Business Finance and Accounting. 2006;33(7&8):1034-62. . ;:. Google Scholar
  23. Zahra SA, Pearce JA. Boards of directors and corporate financial performance: A review and integrative model. Journal of Management. 1989;15(2):291-334. . ;:. Google Scholar
  24. Bonn I, Yoshikawa T, Phan PH. Effects of board structure on firm performance: A comparison between Japan and Australia. Asian Business & Management. 2004;3(1):105-25. . ;:. Google Scholar
  25. Mak YT, Li Y. Determinants of corporate ownership and board structure: Evidence from Singapore. Journal of Corporate Finance. 2001;7(3):235-56. . ;:. Google Scholar
  26. Muth M, Donaldson L. Stewardship theory and board structure: A contingency approach. Corporate Governance: An International Review. 1998;6(1):5-28. . ;:. Google Scholar
  27. Pfeffer J. Size, composition, and function of hospital boards of directors: A study of organization-environment linkage. Administrative Science Quarterly. 1973;18(3):349-64. . ;:. Google Scholar
  28. Boyd B. Corporate linkages and organizational environment: A test of the resource dependence model. Strategic Management Journal. 1990;11(6):419-30. . ;:. Google Scholar
  29. Hillman AJ, Cannella AA, Paetzold RL. The resource dependence role of corporate directors: Strategic adaptation of board composition in response to environmental change. Journal of Management Studies. 2000;37(2):235-56. . ;:. Google Scholar
  30. Young MN, Ahlstrom D, Bruton GD, Chan ES. The resource dependence, service, and control functions of boards of directors in Hong Kong and Taiwanese firms. Asia Pacific Journal of Management. 2001;18(2):223-44. . ;:. Google Scholar
  31. North DC. Institutions. Journal of Economic Perspectives. 1991;5(1):97-112. . ;:. Google Scholar
  32. Ahrens T, Filatotchev I, Thomsen S. The research frontier in corporate governance. Journal of Management and Governance. 2011;15(3):311-25. . ;:. Google Scholar
  33. Aguilera RV, Filatotchev I, Gospel H, Jackson G. An organizational approach to comparative corporate governance: Costs, contingencies, and complementarities. Organization Science. 2008;19(3):475-92. . ;:. Google Scholar
  34. Aguilera RV, Jackson G. The cross-national diversity of corporate governance: Dimensions and determinants. Academy of Management Review. 2003;28(3):447-65. . ;:. Google Scholar
  35. Luoma P, Goodstein J. Stakeholders, and corporate boards: Institutional influences on board composition and structure. Academy of Management journal. 1999;42(5):553-63. . ;:. Google Scholar
  36. Zattoni A, Cuomo F. Why adopt codes of good governance? A comparison of institutional and efficiency perspectives. Corporate Governance: An International Review. 2008;16(1):1-15. . ;:. Google Scholar
  37. Davies M, Schlitzer B. The impracticality of an international "one size fits all" corporate governance code of best practice. Managerial Auditing Journal. 2008;23(6):532-44. . ;:. Google Scholar
  38. Millar CCJM, Eldomiaty TI, Choi CJ, Hilton B. Corporate governance and institutional transparency in emerging markets. Journal of Business Ethics. 2005;59(1):163-74. . ;:. Google Scholar
  39. La Porta R, Lopez-de-Silanes F, Shleifer A, Vishny R. Legal determinants of external finance. The Journal of Finance. 1997;52(3):1131-50. . ;:. Google Scholar
  40. Chuanrommanee W, Swierczek FW. Corporate governance in ASEAN financial corporations: Reality or illusion? Corporate Governance: An International Review. 2007;15(2):272-83. . ;:. Google Scholar
  41. Nguyen T. Do female directors add value? Acta Universitatis Danubius Œconomica. 2017;13(3):169-77. . ;:. Google Scholar
  42. Nguyen T, Nguyen T. Corporate governance structures and performance of firms in Asian market: A comparative analysis between Singapore and Vietnam. Organizations and Markets in Emerging Economies. 2016;7(2):112-40. . ;:. Google Scholar
  43. Cheung SYL, Chan BY. Corporate governance in Asia. Asia Pacific Development Journal. 2004;11(2):1-32. . ;:. Google Scholar
  44. Hu H, Tam O, Tan M. Internal governance mechanisms and firm performance in China. Asia Pacific Journal of Management. 2010;27(4):727-49. . ;:. Google Scholar
  45. Mohammad A-S, Abdussalam A-T. Ownership structure and firm performance: The case of Jordan. Journal of Business Administration. 2005;1(2). . ;:. Google Scholar
  46. Ponnu CH. Corporate governance structures and the performance of Malaysian public listed companies. International Review of Business Research Papers. 2008;4(2):217-30. . ;:. Google Scholar
  47. Tariq Y, Butt SA. Impact of corporate governance practices on financial performance: Empirical evidence from Pakistan. The 8th Annual Hawaii international conference on business (May 22-25, 2008); Honolulu, USA: SSRN; 2008. . ;:. Google Scholar
  48. Reddy K. The relationship between corporate governance practices and financial performance in New Zealand: An empirical investigation [Doctoral thesis]. Hamilton: The University of Waikato; 2010. . ;:. Google Scholar
  49. Donaldson L, Davis JH. Stewardship theory or agency theory: CEO governance and shareholder returns. Australian Journal of Management. 1991;16(1):49-65. . ;:. Google Scholar
  50. Fama EF, Jensen M. Separation of ownership and control. Journal of Law and Economics. 1983;26(2):301-25. . ;:. Google Scholar
  51. Dalton DR, Daily CM, Johnson JL, Ellstrand AE. Number of directors and financial performance: A meta-analysis. Academy of Management journal. 1999:674-86. . ;:. Google Scholar
  52. Jensen M. Modern industrial revolution, exit, and the failure of internal control systems. Journal of Finance. 1993; 48:831-80. . ;:. Google Scholar
  53. Lipton M, Lorsch JW. A modest proposal for improved corporate governance. Business Lawyer. 1992;48(1):59-77. . ;:. Google Scholar
  54. Sonnenfeld JA. What makes great boards great. Harvard Business Review. 2002;80(9):106-13. . ;:. Google Scholar
  55. Yermack D. Higher market valuation of companies with a small board of directors. Journal of Financial Economics. 1996;40(2):185-211. . ;:. Google Scholar
  56. Garg AK. Influence of board size and independence on firm performance: A study of Indian companies. Vikalpa. 2007;32(3):39. . ;:. Google Scholar
  57. Mak YT, Kusnadi Y. Size really matters: Further evidence on the negative relationship between board size and firm value. Pacific-Basin Finance Journal. 2005;13(3):301-18. . ;:. Google Scholar
  58. Beiner S, Drobetz W, Schmid MM, Zimmermann H. An integrated framework of corporate governance and firm valuation. European Financial Management. 2006;12(2):249-83. . ;:. Google Scholar
  59. Maassen GF. An international comparison of corporate governance models. 3 ed. DZ Amsterdam, The Netherlands: Spencer Stuart; 2002. . ;:. Google Scholar
  60. Nguyen A, Nguyen T. Working capital management and corporate profitability: Empirical evidence from Vietnam. Foundations of Management. 2018;10(1):195-206. . ;:. Google Scholar
  61. Nguyen A, Nguyen T. Free cash flow and corporate profitability in emerging economies: Empirical evidence from Vietnam. Economics Bulletin. 2018;38(1):211-20. . ;:. Google Scholar
  62. Bozec R. Boards of directors, market discipline and firm performance. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting. 2005;32(9 & 10):1921-60. . ;:. Google Scholar
  63. Shleifer A, Vishny RW. Large shareholders and corporate control. Journal of Political Economy. 1986;94(3):461-88. . ;:. Google Scholar
  64. La Porta R, Lopez-de-Silanes F, Shleifer A, Vishny R. Investor protection and corporate governance. Journal of Financial Economics. 2000;58(1&2):3-27. . ;:. Google Scholar
  65. Ntim CG. Internal corporate governance structures and firm financial performance: Evidence from South African listed firms [Doctoral thesis]: University of Glasgow; 2009. . ;:. Google Scholar
  66. Morck R, Shleifer A, Vishny RW. Management ownership and market valuation: An empirical analysis. Journal of Financial Economics. 1988;20:293-315. . ;:. Google Scholar


Author's Affiliation
Article Details

Issue: Vol 5 No 3 (2021)
Page No.: 1638-1647
Published: Jun 9, 2021
Section: Review
DOI: https://doi.org/10.32508/stdjelm.v5i3.781

 Copyright Info

Creative Commons License

Copyright: The Authors. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License CC-BY 4.0., which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original author and source are credited.

 How to Cite
Tuấn, N. (2021). Mainstream theories of corporate governance and the corporate governance – firm performance relationship. Science & Technology Development Journal: Economics- Law & Management, 5(3), 1638-1647. https://doi.org/https://doi.org/10.32508/stdjelm.v5i3.781

 Cited by



Article level Metrics by Paperbuzz/Impactstory
Article level Metrics by Altmetrics

 Article Statistics
HTML = 98577 times
Download   = 980 times
View Article   = 0 times
Total   = 980 times